I have recently read a speech by Spencer Dale, who is chief economist at the Bank of England, warning that if growth continues to remain weak, we should be wary about automatically resorting to printing money. Here is my summary followed by the full speech:
Summary:
The policy actions undertaken by the MPC have undeniably played a critical
role in stabilising our economy. Although those actions may bring with them potential risks and costs, the risks of
monetary inaction at a time when our economy was teetering at the edge of a
great depression were far greater.
Monetary policy can do more. If the economic outlook
deteriorates further, policy can respond. We have not yet run out of road. But there are limits to how much we should ask of monetary policy.
We need to remember how little we know about the economy and how it works.
Beware confident economists.
If output growth remains weak, we will need to assess carefully developments
in potential supply as well as demand before deciding how to respond. The
rates of growth enjoyed prior to the crisis may not be the correct benchmark
for the next few years.
And we need to consider the potential costs as well as benefits of further
policy easing. We are in uncharted – and potentially dangerous - water.
Full Speech:
"Monetary policy has been pushed into situations and actions that were
previously unimaginable.
These challenges – and the strains they have placed on monetary policy –
provide the focus for my remarks today.
What role is it realistic to expect monetary policy to play – what role can it
play - as we try to recover from the financial crisis?
What are the limits of monetary policy?
I want to consider two dimensions of these potential limits.
First, and most broadly, the role monetary policy can play in trying to
support a recovery in aggregate demand.
The financial crisis and subsequent recession has increased the focus on using
monetary policy to stabilise the economy. In part, this was driven by the
well justified fears that the deep recession could lead to deflation. But
over and above that, it was a response to the widespread presumption that
monetary policy could – and indeed should – play an active stabilisation
role. For better or worse, we have come to expect more of monetary policy
than simply maintaining price stability.
But the greater the ambition of monetary policy, the greater is the required
understanding of the economy: of the shocks driving it; and of the key
relationships underpinning its behaviour. Surely one lesson we have learnt
from the financial crisis – perhaps the most important lesson - is that
economists and policymakers know far less about the economy and its
behaviour than many might have liked to believe.
What are the practical limits to stabilisation policy when there is so much
about the economy we do not, and cannot, know?
The second limitation I want to explore concerns the more specific issue of
the potential costs and side effects of running extremely loose monetary
policy for a sustained period.
Policy rates in the major advanced economies have been close to zero for over
three years. Central bank balance sheets have expanded beyond recognition as
policy committees have pumped increasing amounts of money into the economy.
And, more recently, a number of central banks – including my own – have
provided liquidity and funding support to the banking system on a scale and
in a manner that would, in more normal times, have been pretty unpalatable.
Make no mistake, there are strong arguments for all of these actions. Although
our economy remains weak, I have no doubt that, had these actions not been
taken, it would be in a far worse state today. But prolonged and aggressive
monetary accommodation comes with potential costs and risks: to the long-run
health and functioning of the economy; and potentially to the role and
credibility of central banks.
How much further can monetary policy be pushed until the potential costs and
risks outweigh the benefits?
Recognition of this uncertainty has long been a key feature of the Bank’s
approach to monetary policy. For example, with the use of fan charts in our
Inflation Reports which explicitly depict the considerable uncertainty
surrounding economic forecasts.
Limits to stabilising the economy using monetary policy
Let me start with the broader issue of the potential limits to using monetary
policy to stabilise the economy when our knowledge of how it works is
clouded by uncertainty and ignorance.
An awareness of the limits to our understanding of monetary policy has long
been recognised, dating back at least 60 years or so to Milton Friedman
(1948).
Taken to its extreme, this viewpoint argues that there is little or no scope
for monetary policy to smooth economic cycles. Sticky wages and prices may
very well imply the existence of short-run trade-offs between output and
inflation. But the complexity of the economy means it is beyond the wit of
policymakers to exploit those trade-offs successfully. Trying to do so is
prone to amplify business cycle fluctuations rather than smooth them.
Friedman’s ‘long and variable lags’ pose a constraint on what policymakers
should aspire to achieve.
Under this view, the best that monetary policy can do is to maintain the
nominal standard. In modern parlance: decide on your inflation target and
dedicate monetary policy to achieving it – on average – over long sweeps of
time. Hence Friedman’s k% rule for money growth.
Compared with modern perceptions of the active role monetary policy should
play, sentiments such as those underpinning the k% rule seem rather
antiquated. Central bankers today are at pains to stress that they don’t
focus simply on inflation.
Such sentiments also appear defeatist. Surely we know enough to do better than
simply achieve a target for trend inflation?
That may well be right. But you don’t have to look back very far to see what
can happen when monetary policy fails to achieve even this seemingly modest
objective. In the UK, we saw firsthand in the high and
variable inflation rates of the 1970s and 80s, the cost of monetary policy
taking its eye off the ball.
The belief that we do know more – that we can do better than simply behaving
as inflation nutters – is embodied in modern-day flexible inflation
targeting. This gives primacy to monetary policy maintaining low and stable
inflation, but posits that policymakers also know enough to have some scope
to smooth short-run fluctuations in output.
This seems eminently reasonable and entirely consistent with the broad
consensus within the economics profession.
But remember, we don’t fully understand the structure of the economy or the
behaviour of households and companies within it. Not even close. And we
don’t know the nature of the shocks affecting the economy, even long after
they have occurred.
Is there a danger that we might do more harm than good?
I fear that this may sound too cautious, even wimpy. Surely it can’t be that
difficult?
Or can it?
One way to illustrate the practical difficulty of making the judgements
required to set monetary policy to conform to this modern day consensus is
to consider the policy prescriptions implied by a simple feedback rule, in
this case the most basic form of Taylor rule
The green line in Chart 1 shows the interest rate implied by a simple “plain
vanilla” Taylor rule applied to the UK economy. This suggests that – were it
not for the zero lower bound – Bank Rate should have been set close to -2%
or so in the first quarter of 2012.
But this policy prescription depends critically on the judgements that are fed
into this calibration.
For example, the basic Taylor Rule implies that policy should respond to the
current level of inflation. But over much of the past five years, the UK has
been hit by a series of price level shocks, which should affect inflation
only temporarily and which the MPC has chosen to look through. That might
suggest that policy should feedback from a forecast of medium-term
inflation, once such price level effects have dropped out of the inflation
calculation. If instead we allowed policy to feed back from the MPC’s
forecast for inflation two-years ahead, this would move the implied policy
path even lower, to the yellow line.
As you well know, the policy path implied by the Taylor rule also depends
critically on the assumed size of the output gap.
The output gap used in the plain vanilla rule has been calculated – as in
Taylor’s original paper – by taking deviations of output from its historical
trend. Output in the UK is around 15% or so below where it would have been
had the economy continued to grow in line with its pre-crisis trend. Hence,
the prescription for extremely loose policy.
But a striking feature of the financial crisis and ensuing recession is that
it appears to have affected the growth of the supply capacity of our economy
as well as demand. Despite the apparent deficiency of demand, business
surveys suggest that spare capacity within companies is relatively limited.
Unemployment has risen, but by far less than might have been feared given
the severity of the recession. The counterpart is that private sector
productivity fell sharply and has essentially flat lined over the past
couple of years.
If we use an alternative measure of the output gap, constructed by combining a
simple measure of labour market disequilibrium with a measure of capacity
utilisation within companies, the implied policy path shifts dramatically
upwards to the blue line.
The Taylor rule also requires a judgement about the equilibrium level of real
interest rates. This embodies all the uncertainty about what is happening on
the supply side of economy. It also requires us to make a judgement about
the extent to which the crisis has affected the functioning of financial
markets. As an illustration, if we used the increase in financial spreads as
a proxy for the extent to which policy has had to ease to offset the
tightening in credit conditions, we get the brown line.
By way of comparison, Chart 2 compares the range of policy paths implied by
these different versions of the Taylor rule with a very crude estimate of
the shadow policy rate set by the MPC, in which I have used a rough
rule-of-thumb to convert the estimated impact of the MPC’s asset purchases
into an equivalent cut in Bank Rate.
The estimate of the path of the shadow Bank Rate has been within the range of
policy rules for much of the recent period. But that is hardly saying very
much given how wide that range has been in recent years. And that is
precisely the point! Even trying to calibrate the simplest Taylor rule can
lead to vastly different policy recommendations depending on the judgements
that are made.
Monetary policymakers face substantial uncertainty. That is not defeatist or
wimpy; it is a fact of life. And it needs to be borne in mind when deciding
how ambitious we should be in our monetary policy objectives.
Let me bring this closer to home and consider some of the issues currently
facing the MPC when assessing the scope for monetary policy to stabilise
output.
In days gone by, if one of my predecessors had observed a slowdown in output
growth, a natural response might have been to assume that this was likely to
increase economic slack and so lower future inflation. The obvious policy
response to such a development would have been to loosen monetary policy in
order to smooth output growth and keep inflation close to target.
Indeed, UK monetary policy during the Great Moderation can be mimicked quite
well by a policy rule defined in terms of keeping output growth close to its
historical trend rate.
But, as we’ve seen, a defining feature of the UK economy since the financial
crisis is that the persistent weakness in output has been accompanied by a
long-lasting period of very weak productivity growth, suggesting that the
supply capacity of the economy may also have been impaired. This makes
judging the appropriate policy response to a slowdown in output growth far
more complicated.
Loosening policy further in response to weaker output might well be the right
thing to do.
That would be the case, for example, if we judged that growth in supply
capacity is not as weak as the available data might suggest. Rather, spare
capacity may be exerting only a limited drag on inflation and there is some
other explanation for the flat lining in productivity.
It might also be the right thing to do if we judged that the growth in supply
capacity had indeed been muted, but that this was largely due to the lack of
demand. For example, when demand is weak, many companies are likely to have
to devote more resources to finding new customers and pitching for orders to
generate the same amount of business. In this case, stimulating additional
demand would bring with it stronger productivity growth, and would allow the
economy to grow without generating higher inflation.
But injecting additional monetary stimulus when we observe weak output might
not be the right thing to do.
In particular, if we thought weakness in both demand and supply were being
driven by some other factor, perhaps related to our impaired financial
system and the sustained period of tight credit conditions. In this case,
further demand stimulus may run up against supply capacity relatively
quickly and so largely result in higher inflation.
If the handbrake on your car is stuck, putting your foot further and further
down on the accelerator won’t get you very far before the car starts to
overheat.
A significant element of this thinking is reflected in the forecasts for
growth and inflation that the Monetary Policy Committee published last month
in its August Inflation Report. Even though GDP was expected to grow by far
less than its historical trend rate over the next three years, the risks
around the inflation target by the end of the forecast period were thought
to be broadly balanced. This despite the Committee judging that there is
currently a sizeable degree of spare capacity in the economy.
These are difficult judgements and ones that the MPC is having to confront in
real time at its policy meetings.
There are no simple answers. But the Pavlovian-like response of some
commentators to call for more monetary stimulus each time they observe weak
growth is not sensible. The extent to which policy should be eased further
depends crucially on the reasons why output is weak. Using monetary policy
to stabilise the economy is challenging even in the best of times. The
constraints posed by our uncertainty and ignorance should not be
underestimated, particularly so when, as now, the performance of the supply
side of the economy is highly uncertain. Moreover, there may be little that
monetary policy can do to stimulate productivity growth. We need to be
conscious of our limitations when setting policy.
Our economy remains weak. Unemployment has edged down in recent months but it
remains too high. The onus on monetary policy is to continue to stimulate
the economy. But ultimately, our job is to hit an inflation target not a
growth target.
Limits to persistently loose monetary policy
Let me turn now to the more specific question of the limits to running
extremely loose monetary policy for a sustained period of time. How much
further can we push monetary policy before the potential costs risk
outweighing the benefits?
It is clear that the financial crisis has taken monetary policy into uncharted
waters.
In the UK, as in almost every other advanced economy, the size of the fallout
from the financial crisis meant that we quickly exhausted our conventional
policy tools. Bank Rate was cut from 5% to 0.5% in the space of 6 months.
We turned next to large scale asset purchases – QE – which we conducted on a
massive scale. To date, the MPC’s planned asset purchases amount to 25% of
nominal GDP.
There are obviously uncertainties in judging just how effective those actions
have been. Some commentators have pointed to the weakness of growth over the
past couple of years as evidence that their impact has been relatively
limited. But this seems a silly argument. The scale of the headwinds
affecting our economy over this period – in terms of the squeeze in
households’ real incomes stemming from the rise in commodity and other
import prices, the fiscal consolidation, the tightening in credit
conditions, and the fallout from the euro zone crisis – has been huge. These
headwinds have to be taken into account when assessing the effectiveness of
the policy actions taken to offset them. There is a legitimate debate as to
exactly how effective our policy actions to date have been. But I have
little doubt that without them our economy would be in a far worse state
today.
Most recently, the Bank, together with the Government, has launched the
Funding for Lending Scheme (FLS), which provides banks with an alternative
cheaper source of funding tied to the extent to which they expand lending to
the UK real economy.
I can understand why to some households and companies who have been unable to
borrow in recent years this may just sound like yet another in a long line
of schemes to get the banks lending.
But the Funding for Lending Scheme is different. It is bigger and bolder than
any scheme tried so far to get the banks lending. In terms of the cost at
which funding is being made available, the maturity of that funding and,
most importantly, the strong price incentives it provides to banks to expand
their lending.
By helping to improve the availability of bank lending to companies and
households who previously have been effectively starved of credit, it could
have a significant effect on demand. Moreover, if some of the recent poor
supply side performance of our economy does stem from the constraints on the
flow of credit, it may also help to ease that friction.
Of course, the FLS is not a magic wand likely to resolve all impediments to
lending growth. Despite the incentives provided by the scheme, some banks
may remain focussed on reducing the size of their balance sheet. And even if
loan rates do fall, some households and companies may be wary of increasing
their levels of borrowing in the current economic climate. But the FLS takes
off the table the constraint posed by high bank funding costs. And in my
view stands a good chance of making a material difference.
But prolonged and aggressive monetary accommodation, combined with
increasingly unconventional policy tools, also comes with potential costs
and risks. We need to be alert to those pitfalls when assessing the strain
that should be placed on monetary policy.
These costs and risks may manifest themselves in at least three different
ways: unwelcome side effects; exit risks; and the impact on our credibility.
Let me consider each of these in turn.
Monetary policy, by reducing short term interest rates and improving the
availability of credit, encourages households and companies to bring forward
their spending. To borrow more and save less. That is exactly what is needed
in a period of deficient demand. But there are potential unwelcome side
effects associated with a sustained period of loose monetary policy.
For example, a recent literature has highlighted the possibility of a
so-called ‘risk taking channel’ of monetary policy. As policy rates are
reduced and the yield on short-term safe assets fall, investors may shift
their portfolios towards increasingly risky assets. This is perhaps
particularly likely to be the case if some institutional investors have to
target nominal rates of return in order to match those on their liabilities.
This might well be a good thing if risk premia are too high and there is
insufficient risk taking. But it could also store up problems for the
future. Rajan (2006), for example, argues that this search for yield was a
key factor driving the increase in risk taking in the run-up to the crisis.
In a similar vein, QE works by encouraging institutional investors to hold an
increasingly risky portfolio of assets. This helps to increase the demand
for debt and equity issued by UK companies. But it comes at the expense of
increasing the risks borne by key parts of our financial sector.
More generally, the prolonged period of low interest rates and enhanced
support may delay some of the rebalancing and restructuring that our economy
needs to undertake. Underlying balance sheet problems can be masked,
tempering the incentives to address them. Inefficient firms may remain in
business for longer and so slow the reallocation of capital and labour to
more productive uses. Low interest rates and the associated forbearance
might even explain part of the puzzling weakness in productivity.
Monetary policy can and should provide short-term support in times of need,
but it must avoid becoming a long-term crutch obstructing the required
rebalancing of our economy.
Consider next the possible risks as we begin to exit from this prolonged
period of very loose monetary policy.
At first blush moving to a more normal stance of policy as conditions improve
appears relatively straightforward. The structure of UK money markets means
that we can raise Bank Rate at any point; there is no need for us to first
drain the excess reserves held by the banking system. We will be selling the
gilts we hold back into one of the deepest and most liquid sovereign debt
markets in the world. And we have worked closely with the Debt Management
Office to consider how this might be best achieved.
But we should also recognise that we need to sell a huge amount of gilts back
to private sector investors: around 40% of the total stock of conventional
gilts. That will require a corresponding reduction in the other types of
assets held by private sector investors. Achieving this portfolio
rebalancing without unsettling the government bond market and, equally
important, causing a substantial crowding out of private sector debt will be
a delicate task.
Finally, consider the potential threats to the MPC’s credibility.
The most obvious stems from the inevitable blurring between fiscal and
monetary policy when interest rates are close to zero. The purchase of vast
quantities of government debt provides an efficient and effective way of
injecting into our economy the substantial amounts of liquidity judged
necessary to hit the inflation target in the medium term. That is the reason
– and the only reason – why QE is being undertaken. But to some observers,
QE may look uncomfortably close to monetary financing. The difference will
become apparent when we sell the gilts back to the private sector as the
economy begins to normalise. But that may well be some way off. And in the
meantime, it may look to some a little too convenient that we are choosing
to hold vast quantities of government debt at a time when the fiscal deficit
remains around post-war highs. However unfounded, those perceptions need to
be taken seriously.
More generally, I worry that unless the limits of monetary policy are well
understood, a widening gap may develop between what is expected of central
banks and what they can realistically deliver. Central banks need to be
clear about the limits of monetary policy in order to protect our long-term
trust and legitimacy."
Source: Telegraph
No comments:
Post a Comment